Euromarkets
Article pour le
Palgrave Dictionnary of Transnational
History (P.Y. Saunier et A.
Iriye, eds)
Euromarkets (occasionally called
‘xenomarkets’) are markets on which banks deal in a currency other than
their
own. For example, eurodollars are dollars held by banks outside the United States.
The prefix ‘euro’ refers to the fact that such deposits first appeared
in Europe in around 1955. The origins
of the eurodollar are
traceable partly to the Cold War, when the USSR
(in particular) desperately needed international liquidity – dollars - but did not want to hold them in the United States.
The rise of the dollar as an international currency encouraged
companies
world-wide to hold dollar cash reserves, and banks to ask for dollars
on
deposit. Some countries decided that such deposits did not need to be
so
closely regulated as deposits in the national currency because they did
not
affect the internal money supply. This produced a very liberal loan
market,
particularly in comparison with the prevailing heavy post-war
regulation. On
top of that, America’s
Q regulation (put in place by the 1933 Glass Steagall Act) set a
ceiling on the
interest rates payable on bank deposits and so savers looked for more
attractive rates elsewhere. Similarly, eurobonds benefited from an
equalisation
tax imposed in 1963 on interest payable on foreign issues placed in the
USA.
London
played a key role
in the development of euromarkets. Eurodollar loans, still negligible
in 1958,
rose to 25 billion dollars in 1968 and 130 billion in 1973. At that
time London accounted for almost 80% of
the market, which was
still largely controlled by London
branches of foreign banks – mostly American, but also some French,
Japanese and
German. By 1975 there were 243 such subsidiaries in London.
While
the main incentive for the development of euromarkets was the avoidance
of
national regulations, their development also helped to weaken those
same
regulations by providing both borrowers and lenders with alternatives
to
nationally regulated solutions. The logical outcome of euromarkets was
the
liberalisation of capital movements. They undoubtedly represented one
nail in
the coffin of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate scheme, which
assumed that
central banks were capable of controlling exchange rates; this they
could only
do if they could control capital flows, at least in the short term.
At
present, the term ‘euromarket’ is less often employed, since lending in
a
currency other than that of the borrower or lender has now become
commonplace.
Pierre-Cyrille
Hautcoeur
<>
Further
reading >
Bakker, A. F., 1996. The Liberalization of Capital Movements in Europe
: The Monetary Committee and Financial Integration, 1958-1994. Dordrecht:
Kluwer.
<>Schenk, Catherine, 1998. "The origins
of the Eurodollar Market in London,
1955-1963", Explorations in Economic History, 35.>
Kerr, I.
M.m
(ed.), 1984. A History of the
Eurobond Market. The First
21 Years. London:
Euromoney Publications.
Cross
references: loans, financial markets,
financial
centres